Coalgate uproar is overdone
What to privatise,
when to privatise and how to privatise are amongst the important policy
questions in the transition from state to market. The uproar over
Coalgate tells us, as the uproar over the sale of 2G spectrum did
earlier, that India is still learning how these questions are best
addressed.
Privatisation is not primarily about raising resources
for the government. It is about improving efficiency in the economy.
Most people believe that the private sector is always more efficient
than the government and that the government has 'no business to be in
business'.
The literature on privatisation suggests that the
reality is rather more nuanced. For instance, in regulated industries,
there is not much of a difference in efficiency between the two sectors.
Moreover, privatisation works only when certain stringent conditions
are met: the sale of assets happens through an efficient auction, there
is adequate competition and institutions are strong. Before rushing to
judgement on Coalgate, it is worth examining how some of these
considerations would apply to the sale of a natural resource, such as
coal.
Coal mining is overwhelmingly the responsibility of Coal
India Limited (CIL). The first question to ask is whether it is CIL's
inefficiency that warrants the entry of private players. As the CAG
report notes, CIL has done a good job of meeting its internal targets
but fallen short of the Planning Commission's higher targets. This,
however, cannot be ascribed to inefficiency on the part of CIL.
CIL
has faced several obstacles in mining coal, for instance, rail links
from mining areas were not available nor was heavy earth-moving
equipment. Land acquisition and environment clearances posed serious
hurdles. For these very reasons, several private parties have not been
able to make much headway with the blocks taken away from CIL (against
its wishes) and allotted to them.
Secondly, since competition is
more important than ownership, it would have been sensible to first
restructure CIL and create competitive conditions within the public
sector itself. CIL should have been listed long before it was in 2010.
Some of its subsidiaries might have been spun off into competing, listed
companies.
Thirdly, we need to recognise that CIL
is able to supply coal at a discount of 26-77% to the international
price. This has implications for private sector entry into the sector.
If bidding is to be truly competitive, we have to allow international
bidders. This has the potential to raise coal prices to international
levels. If, on the other hand, we wish to regulate coal prices, there
may not be enough bidders and the revenues accruing to the government
would be much lower. Moreover, since such an auction would be
inefficient, the fundamental objective of achieving efficiency in the
coal sector itself may be defeated.
Turn now to the issues involved in
Coalgate. The CAG has said that the coal blocks for captive mining
should have been allocated on the basis of competitive bidding. Had this
been done, it could well have raised the coal price at captive mines to
the price of imports.
In computing the net gain to
private parties, the CAG has used the average sale price of CIL in
2010-11. The CAG has not discounted the stream of net benefit and it has
been criticised on this account. The discounted value comes to Rs
58,000 crore (assuming a life of 30 years for a mine and the discount
rate of 10% used by the CAG in the case of the Delhi airport) or an
average value of Rs 1,027 crore for 57 private mines. The CAG's higher
estimate of net gain, Rs 1,85,591 crore, can be justified only under the
assumption that the sale price of coal would catch up with
international prices.
The figure of Rs 1,027 crore
is an average and it is a theoretical upper limit based on the
assumption that bidding would be truly competitive. For a given mine,
there is considerable uncertainty as to extractable reserves, the cost
of mining, the quality of coal and the time taken for regulatory
clearances. In many cases, the bids would be much lower; in some, there
may not be bidders at all.
Any windfall gains on the
mines would be reflected in profits made in the end-uses and would be
taxed. The notional loss to government is thus almost certainly way
below Rs 58,000 crore.
It was open to the government to attempt
competitive bidding for a few mines, subject to a reserve price (and
using the price of coal as a bid parameter). If the response had been
weak, it would have been better placed to resort to allocations.
However, time was of the essence. There was concern about the impact of
competitive bidding on coal prices. Legislation was thought necessary,
and enacting it would take time.
These are valid reasons for going down
the allocation route. Where the government went wrong was in not
following transparent criteria in making allocations. We know now that
several political parties were complicit in the manipulation of
allocations. It does not follow, however, that the allocation policy per
se was flawed.
The government has justified the
first-come-first-served policy in the sale of 2G spectrum on the ground
that it helped keep the rates on mobile telephony low.
A similar
case can be made for the allocation of coal blocks. In the design of
privatisation, a choice has often to be made between revenue
maximisation and other objectives such as keeping the price to the
end-user low. It does not make sense to cry 'scam' whenever the
government opts for the latter.
Privatisation is not primarily about raising resources for the government. It is about improving efficiency in the economy. Most people believe that the private sector is always more efficient than the government and that the government has 'no business to be in business'.
The literature on privatisation suggests that the reality is rather more nuanced. For instance, in regulated industries, there is not much of a difference in efficiency between the two sectors. Moreover, privatisation works only when certain stringent conditions are met: the sale of assets happens through an efficient auction, there is adequate competition and institutions are strong. Before rushing to judgement on Coalgate, it is worth examining how some of these considerations would apply to the sale of a natural resource, such as coal.
Coal mining is overwhelmingly the responsibility of Coal India Limited (CIL). The first question to ask is whether it is CIL's inefficiency that warrants the entry of private players. As the CAG report notes, CIL has done a good job of meeting its internal targets but fallen short of the Planning Commission's higher targets. This, however, cannot be ascribed to inefficiency on the part of CIL.
CIL has faced several obstacles in mining coal, for instance, rail links from mining areas were not available nor was heavy earth-moving equipment. Land acquisition and environment clearances posed serious hurdles. For these very reasons, several private parties have not been able to make much headway with the blocks taken away from CIL (against its wishes) and allotted to them.

Thirdly, we need to recognise that CIL is able to supply coal at a discount of 26-77% to the international price. This has implications for private sector entry into the sector. If bidding is to be truly competitive, we have to allow international bidders. This has the potential to raise coal prices to international levels. If, on the other hand, we wish to regulate coal prices, there may not be enough bidders and the revenues accruing to the government would be much lower. Moreover, since such an auction would be inefficient, the fundamental objective of achieving efficiency in the coal sector itself may be defeated.
In computing the net gain to private parties, the CAG has used the average sale price of CIL in 2010-11. The CAG has not discounted the stream of net benefit and it has been criticised on this account. The discounted value comes to Rs 58,000 crore (assuming a life of 30 years for a mine and the discount rate of 10% used by the CAG in the case of the Delhi airport) or an average value of Rs 1,027 crore for 57 private mines. The CAG's higher estimate of net gain, Rs 1,85,591 crore, can be justified only under the assumption that the sale price of coal would catch up with international prices.
The figure of Rs 1,027 crore is an average and it is a theoretical upper limit based on the assumption that bidding would be truly competitive. For a given mine, there is considerable uncertainty as to extractable reserves, the cost of mining, the quality of coal and the time taken for regulatory clearances. In many cases, the bids would be much lower; in some, there may not be bidders at all.
Any windfall gains on the mines would be reflected in profits made in the end-uses and would be taxed. The notional loss to government is thus almost certainly way below Rs 58,000 crore.
The government has justified the first-come-first-served policy in the sale of 2G spectrum on the ground that it helped keep the rates on mobile telephony low.
A similar case can be made for the allocation of coal blocks. In the design of privatisation, a choice has often to be made between revenue maximisation and other objectives such as keeping the price to the end-user low. It does not make sense to cry 'scam' whenever the government opts for the latter.